Episodes
Sunday Aug 12, 2018
Sunday Aug 12, 2018
Tim's speech from Porcfest 2018 expands on the ideas he presented in his previous speech, and presents a more cohesive framework for addressing issues related to Public Space within libertarian theory. He challenges some libertarian orthodoxy, in particular Hans-Hermann Hoppe's conception of public space as simply an extension of private property.
Also: Helicopters ššš
Use hashtag #ana019 to reference this episode in a tweet, post, or comment.
View full show notes at https://anarchitecturepodcast.com/ana019.
Download Slideshow as PDF
Speech Notes
Note: YouTube with slideshow coming soon.
PorcFest XV | June 21, 2018
āProperty is theft; Property is freedom: these two propositions stand side by side...
and each is shown to be trueā - Pierre-Joseph ProudhonFrom Selected Writings of Pierre-Joseph Proudhon, ed. Stewart Edwards, Macmillan 1969. p.133
Public Space Is Where Freedom Happens
Public Space: Space that is accessible to non-owners without invitation, with reasonable restrictions
Not always āpublic property.ā Government owned and privately owned
Many types of public space - Open Space, Buildings, Pathways
Degrees of access with permissions
Restrictions on entry and occupancy ā Fees, hours, use, behavior
Many private facilities have public space components (i.e. Lobbies)
Expectation of entry (if not occupancy) on most properties
Freedom of Movement
Access - enter and exit, with reasonable restrictions (fees for wear and tear, hours of use, etc.)
Occupancy
Immigration
Freedom of Association
Meet with others
Assembly
Protest
Special Events - Block party, parade, bike race
Freedom of Exchange
Farmersā Market
Boot Sale
Food Trucks
Sidewalk Entrepreneurship
Peer to peer exchange
Satoshi Squares
Freedom to Bear Arms / Self-defense
Transport weapons to private property
Restrictions on self-defense in public spaces may expose the owners of public space to liability for not protecting
occupants
Four Tiers of Public Space
Private Space ā Invitation only / eviction rights.
Maximum freedom for owner, minimal freedoms for public.
Permissive Public Space ā Public access and uses permitted by owner. Revocable defined freedoms.
Protected Public Space ā Public access and uses protected by easement, legal rights, etc. Irrevocable defined freedoms.
Unowned Public Space ā State of nature. Unlimited public access and uses. Maximum freedom for public, potential for conflict.
We should fight for a free society in which public space exists.
How do we divest public space from government ownership and control while preserving the freedom of public space?
Hoppeās Private, Common, and Public Property
Hans-Hermann Hoppe, āOf Private, Common, and Public Property and the Rationale for Total Privatization,ā Libertarian Papers 3, 1 (2011)
Property Ownership as Conflict Avoidance (paraphrased)
Physical conflicts over scarce goods can be avoided if every good is exclusively controlled by some specified individual or group.
To avoid all physical conflict from the beginning of mankind, all property must go back through a chain of conflict-free property title transfers to acts of original appropriation (homesteading).
Hoppeās Village
Unowned / Unused Land (State of Nature)
Unowned Land In Use
Homesteaded Private Property
Homesteaded Private Neighborhood
Public Space Conflict (Scarcity)
Solution 1 - Government-Owned āPublicā Property
Villagers form a government to own and manage the street.
The Government:
Restricts access by villagers and foreigners
Sets rules and regulations
Controls commercial activity and development on street
Requires payment - user fees or taxes
Does not allow exit from ownership
Gains control over abutting private property (encirclement)
Hoppeās Village ā Government-Owned āPublicā Property
Solution 2 ā Homesteaded Private Property
Individual or group āhomesteadsā the road by making repairs, granting them exclusive ownership
The Owner:
Restricts access by villagers and foreigners
Sets rules and regulations
Controls commercial activity and development on street
Requires payment - user fees or taxes subscription
Does not allow exit from joining ownership
Gains control over abutting private property (encirclement)
Hoppeās Village ā Homesteaded Private Property
Solution 2.1 ā Homesteaded Private Property with Easement
Individual or group āhomesteadsā the road by making repairs, granting them exclusive ownership. Villagers are granted a right-of way easement.
The Owner:
Restricts access by villagers and foreigners
Sets rules and regulations
Controls commercial activity and development on street
Requires payment by foreigners only - user fees or taxes subscription
Does not allow exit from joining ownership
Gains control over Restricts foreignersā access to abutting private property (encirclement) (border control)
Hoppeās Village ā Homesteaded Private Property / Easement
Hoppeās Easement Problem:
āFor, by definition, as the first appropriator he cannot have run into any conflict with anyone in appropriating the good in question, as everyone else appeared on the scene only later.ā
Easement means:
First appropriator did run into conflict, with previous users
Use alone creates property rights, not just Lockean labor (improvements)
Property rights can be granted to an unorganized collective (public), not just individual or organized group entity
Property rights are divisible and can be allocated, not just exclusive control.
Modes of Property Ownership
(borrowed from Cynefin project management theory)
Disorder - Unowned land
Simple Ownership ā Property rights allocated to one defined individual or group
Complicated Ownership ā Property rights allocated among multiple defined individuals or groups
Complex Ownership ā Property rights allocated among multiple defined and undefined individuals or groups (i.e. the public)
Chaotic Ownership - Unpredictable allocation of property rights among multiple defined and undefined individuals or groups
Hoppeās Village ā Homesteaded Private Property
Hoppeās Village ā Homesteaded Private Property / Easement
Hoppeās Village ā Protected Public Space
We Need to Talk About Helicopters
āIn a covenant concluded among proprietor and community tenants for the purpose of protecting their private property,
no such thing as a right to free (unlimited) speech exists, not even to unlimited speech on oneās own tenant-property. ā¦no one is permitted to advocate ideas contrary to the very covenant of preserving and protecting private property, such as democracy and communism.
There can be no tolerance toward democrats and communists in a libertarian social order. They will have to be physically separated and removed from society.ā - Hans Herman HoppeDemocracy - The God That Failed: The Economics and Politics of Monarchy, Democracy, and Natural Order (Transaction: 2001) p. 218
A covenant among proprietor and community tenants
What people get wrong about Hoppe
āPhysical Removalā means eviction from private property (Tier 1 Private Space) by its owner. Thatās it. No helicopters, folks.
Hoppeās restrictions on speech are consented to within the covenant community and do not apply outside that community.
What Hoppe gets right:
In a covenant community, property owners can voluntarily agree to mutually restrict their freedoms, including speech about communism.
Covenant violators could be evicted from the community, if allowed by the covenant terms.
This is not aggression. The violator consented to removal.
What Hoppe gets wrong:
"Shh.. The libertarians are listening..."
Covenant community restrictions only apply to property owners
āLibertarianā covenant communities would not choose to restrict speech, movement, etc. even if such covenants were possible, which they arenāt
Collectivized covenant communities are not āa libertarian social order.ā They are communist.
How do covenant communities make decisions? Democracy!
No government-run nation, state, or village is a voluntary covenant community
Private ownership of public space does not necessarily grant the owner right to admit or exclude others.
In a libertarian society, there should be a network of protected public spaces from which you cannot be physically removed.
Divesting Government Property
Why Divest Government Property?
Basis for the stateās power and perceived legitimacy
Private landownership maximizes freedom for landowner and minimizes conflict among permitted users
Protected Public Space can maximize freedom for the public and minimize conflict through negotiated easements / rules
Less justification for eminent domain
Municipal police are not needed to secure private property
Windfall capital endowment for the poor (and everyone else)
Land Available for Homesteading (See table image below)
Methods of Divestiture (See comparison table image below)
To the Taxpayers (Hoppe)
To the Workers
To the Users
To the Abutters
To the Citizens
To the Creditors
To the Victims of History (Restitution)
To the Highest Bidder (Auction)
Lottery
Vouchers
Seizure in revolution
Opt-In Trusts
A form of non-governmental public ownership
Anyone can establish an ownership share at no cost
Anyone can relinquish an ownership share
Owners choose board members / management
Owners have a stake in decision making
Owners receive benefits of ownership (profit)
Owners may be responsible for costs
Owners establish access rights and rules
Creating an Opt-in Trust
Someone creates a Declaration of Trust (legal document)
Defines criteria and process for opting-in
Defines rights and responsibilities of owners and users
Individuals opt-in to claim ownership shares
New owners further evolve Trust policies
Divesting Government Property to an Opt-in Trust
Anarchitecture Podcast convinces governments to divest property
Various Opt-in Trusts compete to persuade government to divest to them
Multiple Opt-in Trusts may merge to be more viable
Government transitions ownership of a specific property to a Trust
Sources of Revenue
Owner Fees (may be limited by Trust)
User Fees (may be limited by easements)
Abutter Impact Fees (curb cuts, utility work)
Utility Fees (purchase easements, work permit fees)
Land-Leases (mining, logging, operators, food trucks, events)
Advertising (billboards, signboards, naming rights)
Donations
Raising Capital For Improvements
Owner Fees (may be limited by Trust)
Investment Shares ā Separate from Opt-In Shares. Proportional to value of improvements
Bonds ā May be collateralized by improvements (not land value)
Asset Sales ā Limited by Trust and easements.
Maintenance Costs
Paid by Trust
Wear and tear
Security
Insurance
Claim Damages
Management / Administrative
Profits
Savings for future improvements
Discounts to users
Dividends to Opt-In Shares. Each additional share dilutes previous shares.
Dividends to Investment Shares. Proportional to value of improvements.
Conclusion
Public space is where freedom happens
4 Tiers ā Private, Permissive, Protected, Unowned
Modes of Ownership ā Disorder, Simple, Complicated, Complex, Chaotic
A libertarian society should have a network of protected public spaces connecting sovereign private properties
Government property should be divested to public forms of ownership with protections for established freedoms
Opt-In Trusts may be the best method of divestiture
Discussion
Lancaster or Lebanon?
Tim was offered a helicopter ride
Helicopter memes - taken too seriously?
Covenant Communities
Red Meat and Sacred Cows
Protected Public Space vs. Hoppean border controls
A more nuanced view - Public Space as a separate category of analysis
"Governing the Commons" - Elinor Ostrom
Separable rights to uses of public space
Aggression defined as "Interference with established use"
Homesteading uses vs. homesteading land
Private public spaces could still exist (e.g. within private gated communities)
Covenant Communities are overrated
Hoppeville is a communist arrangement. That's why the houses were red.
Sovereign private property connected by a network of public space
More on Opt-in Trusts
Two objections
Objection 1: Tragedy of the Commons
Would a market process emerge to convert unsuccessful spaces to other uses?
Road network maintained as a whole - big roads subsidize smaller feeder roads
Objection 2: A trust could become a state
Limited scope of Opt-in Trusts
Opt-in implies Opt-out
How does an Opt-in Trust enforce user fees?
Common law adjudication
Established penalties could inform appropriate user fees
Fees are for service provided, not access per se
Right of eviction for chronic deadbeats
Get these ideas into the literature
Bonus! The sounds of Porcfest (Raw Audio)
Links/Resources
Hans-Hermann Hoppe:
āOf Private, Common, and Public Property and the Rationale for Total Privatization,ā Libertarian Papers 3, 1 (2011). ONLINE AT: libertarianpapers.org.
Democracy - The God That Failed
The Case for Free Trade and Restricted Immigration
Tragedy of the Commons by Garret Hardin
Governing the Commons (PDF) by Elinor Ostrom
Our previous discussions:
ana013: Private Ownership of Public Space | Part 1: Timās Porcfest Speech
ana014: Private Ownership of Public Space | Part 2: Exploring Opt-In Trusts
Images
Images from Tim's slideshow are included in the show notesĀ atĀ https://anarchitecturepodcast.com/ana019.
Comments (0)
To leave or reply to comments, please download free Podbean or
No Comments
To leave or reply to comments,
please download free Podbean App.